Revisión | a828e0fa5fbcfe62bae2e13d31927946f3f3eede (tree) |
---|---|
Tiempo | 2018-12-04 23:45:57 |
Autor | Lorenzo Isella <lorenzo.isella@gmai...> |
Commiter | Lorenzo Isella |
I added an interesting article document in which I modify the margins and the font size.
@@ -0,0 +1,314 @@ | ||
1 | +% \documentclass[12pt,a4paper]{article} | |
2 | +\documentclass[14pt, a4paper]{extarticle} | |
3 | +\usepackage[utf8x]{inputenc} | |
4 | +\usepackage[english]{babel} | |
5 | +\usepackage{url} | |
6 | +\usepackage{graphicx} | |
7 | +\usepackage{amsmath} | |
8 | +\usepackage{xcolor} | |
9 | +\usepackage{caption} | |
10 | +\usepackage{hyperref} | |
11 | +% for placeholder text | |
12 | +\usepackage{lipsum} | |
13 | +\usepackage[margin=0.5in]{geometry} | |
14 | + | |
15 | +\title{Annex to the Note to File: Calculation of the Growth Rate for | |
16 | + FTA and non-FTA Trade} | |
17 | +% \author{Lorenzo Isella} | |
18 | +\date{} | |
19 | + | |
20 | +\begin{document} | |
21 | +\maketitle | |
22 | + | |
23 | +\abstract{ | |
24 | +We give the definitions of growth rate and we introduce the main | |
25 | +formulas for the calculations of the composite growth rate along a | |
26 | +multi-period time span. After illustrating the shortcomings inherent to | |
27 | +a straightforward calculation of the | |
28 | +growth rate of trade flows, we suggest a methodology to bypass these | |
29 | +issues which borrows from the theory of measurement of investment returns. | |
30 | +} | |
31 | +\section{Basic Definitions and Properties of the Growth Rate} | |
32 | + | |
33 | + % In the simplest case, we aim at calculating the growth rate of all the | |
34 | +% trade in the world, regardless of whether it is under FTAs or | |
35 | +% not. In the following, I mainly fix the notation. There are plenty | |
36 | +% of indexes, but we talk about plain vanilla growth rates in the end | |
37 | +% of the day. | |
38 | + | |
39 | +Let $l_{ij}^{t}$ be the value of the trade flow between countries $i$ | |
40 | +and $j$ at year $t$. By definition, the growth rate at time $t$ for | |
41 | +the aforementioned flow is | |
42 | +given by | |
43 | + | |
44 | +\begin{equation}\label{grate} | |
45 | +g_{ij}^{t}=\frac{l_{ij}^{t}-l_{ij}^{t-1}}{l_{ij}^{t-1}} | |
46 | +\end{equation} | |
47 | + | |
48 | +so that | |
49 | + | |
50 | +\begin{equation} | |
51 | +l_{ij}^{t}=l_{ij}^{t-1}(1+g_{ij}^{t}). | |
52 | +\end{equation} | |
53 | + | |
54 | +The value of the world total trade at time $t$ is | |
55 | + | |
56 | +\begin{equation} | |
57 | +l_{world}^{t}=\sum_{ij} l_{ij}^{t} | |
58 | +\end{equation} | |
59 | + | |
60 | +then based on Eq. \eqref{grate}, the growth rate of the world total | |
61 | +trade is | |
62 | + | |
63 | +\begin{equation}\label{totalgrowth} | |
64 | +g_{world}^{t}=\frac{\sum_{ij} l_{ij}^{t} - | |
65 | + l_{ij}^{t-1}}{\sum_{ij} l_{ij}^{t-1}}=\sum_{ij}{w_{ij}^{t} g_{ij}^{t}} | |
66 | +\end{equation} | |
67 | + | |
68 | +i.e. a weighted sum of the growth rates for the individual flows with | |
69 | +weight given by | |
70 | + | |
71 | +\begin{equation} | |
72 | +w_{ij}^{t}=\frac{l_{ij}^{t-1}}{\sum_{ij}l_{ij}^{t-1}}. | |
73 | + \end{equation} | |
74 | + | |
75 | +The meaning of Eq. \eqref{totalgrowth} is transparent: if e.g. a trade flow accounts for 10{\% } of the world trade at | |
76 | +time $t-1$, it will have a weight of 10{\% } in the | |
77 | +calculation | |
78 | +of the | |
79 | +world trade growth at time $t$. % A perfectly analogous formula holds | |
80 | +% for the growth rate of the total trade under (outside) FTAs, where the | |
81 | +% sum in Eq. \eqref{totalgrowth} is restricted to the trade flows under | |
82 | +% (outside) FTAs. | |
83 | +As we will note in Section \ref{fta}, the direct application of | |
84 | +Eq. \eqref{totalgrowth} to the (non-)FTA trade is problematic | |
85 | +whenever, due to the enforcement of an FTA, one or more trade flow | |
86 | +transition from being subject to import duties to being tariff-free. | |
87 | + | |
88 | +% The last step is how to combine the growth rates. | |
89 | +Having at hand a | |
90 | + set of growth rates $\{ g^{t}, g^{t+1},\cdots, g^{t+n} \}$ at years | |
91 | + $\{ t, t+1, \cdots, t+n \}$, we calculate the total growth rate | |
92 | +in the period $[t, t+n]$ as | |
93 | +\begin{equation}\label{composite} | |
94 | + g^{t,t+n}=\prod_{k=0}^{k=n}(1+g^{t+k})-1=(1+g^{t})\times(1+g^{t+1})\times\cdots\times(1-g^{t+n})-1 | |
95 | +\end{equation} | |
96 | +Once a growth rate has been calculated on | |
97 | +any number of consecutive years, it is straightforward to construct | |
98 | +an annualized growth rate which is essentially the geometric average | |
99 | +of the yearly growth rates. For instance, in Eq. \eqref{composite}, the | |
100 | +growth rate is calculated along $n+1$ consecutive years from $t$ to | |
101 | +$t+n$ and the annualized rate is given by | |
102 | +\begin{equation}\label{annualized} | |
103 | + g^{t,t+n}_{\mathrm{annualized}}=(1+g^{t,t+n})^{\frac{1}{n+1}}-1=\{ (1+g^{t})\times(1+g^{t+1})\times\cdots\times(1-g^{t+n})\}^{\frac{1}{n+1}}-1 | |
104 | +\end{equation} | |
105 | + | |
106 | +\section{Issues with (non-)FTA Trade Flows}\label{fta} | |
107 | + The complication arises due to having two classes of trade | |
108 | + flows, namely those under FTAs and those outside FTAs with flows | |
109 | + moving continuously from the non-FTA to the FTA category. | |
110 | + | |
111 | + | |
112 | + | |
113 | +Let us fix the ideas with a small example. We have tree countries | |
114 | +$X$, $Y$ and $Z$ trading with each other as shown in Figure \ref{trade}. | |
115 | + | |
116 | +\begin{figure}[htb] | |
117 | + \begin{center} | |
118 | +\scalebox{.5}{\input{correct.pdf_t}} %the difference is just this part | |
119 | +\caption{Example of trade flows between three countries $X$, $Y$ and $Z$.} | |
120 | +\label{trade} | |
121 | +\end{center} | |
122 | +\end{figure} | |
123 | + | |
124 | + | |
125 | +We have three possible trade flows (we drop the time index in | |
126 | +order not to overburden the notation), namely $l_{XY}$, | |
127 | +$l_{YZ}$ and $l_{XZ}$. Let us assume that we have trade data in the period 2013-2016. $X$ and $Y$ | |
128 | + negotiated an FTA long ago, so the trade between them is always | |
129 | + tariff-free in the period under scrutiny. On the contrary, $Y$ and $Z$ have | |
130 | + never liberalised their trade exchanges. | |
131 | +$X$ and $Y$ negotiated an FTA which entered into force on the $1^{st}$ of | |
132 | +January 2015. | |
133 | +We report the fictitious trade flows between the three | |
134 | +countries in Table \ref{tradeexample}. | |
135 | +Whenever a numerical value is in a | |
136 | +box, it means that the trade is tariff-free, i.e. it occurs under an FTA. | |
137 | + | |
138 | + | |
139 | +\begin{table}[ht] | |
140 | +\centering | |
141 | + % \captionof{table}{Fictitious data about the trade flows between | |
142 | + % countries $X$, $Y$ and $Z$. The box around numerical values indicate | |
143 | + % that the trade takes place under an FTA.} | |
144 | + \caption{Fictitious data about the trade flows between | |
145 | + countries $X$, $Y$ and $Z$. The box around numerical values indicate | |
146 | + that the trade takes place under an FTA.}\label{tradeexample} | |
147 | +\scalebox{1}{ | |
148 | +\begin{tabular}{|r|l|l|l|r|} | |
149 | + \hline | |
150 | +Year & 2013 & 2014 & 2015 & 2016 \\ | |
151 | + \hline | |
152 | +$l_{XY}$ & \boxed{5} & \boxed{5.2} & \boxed{5.1} & \boxed{5.6} \\ | |
153 | + $l_{YZ}$ & 10 & 10.4 & 11.2 & 12.1 \\ | |
154 | + $l_{XZ}$ & 8 & 8.3 & \boxed{8.1} & \boxed{8.7} \\ | |
155 | + \hline | |
156 | + Total FTA Trade & 5 & 5.2 & 13.2 & 14.3 \\ | |
157 | + Total non-FTA Trade & 18 & 18.7 & 11.2 & 12.1 \\ | |
158 | + \hline | |
159 | +\end{tabular} | |
160 | +} | |
161 | +\end{table} | |
162 | + | |
163 | + | |
164 | + | |
165 | +Table \ref{tradetable} exemplifies the issues in the calculation of | |
166 | +the growth rate. If we simply track the amount of trade under FTAs, we | |
167 | +see a huge increase in 2015 due to the entry into force of a new FTA | |
168 | +(inclusion of a new trade flow) and similarly a fall in the trade | |
169 | +outside FTAs for the exclusion of the same trade flow. | |
170 | +As a consequence, the calculation of the growth rate for the total | |
171 | +trade under FTAs or outside FTAs in 2015 would be hugely misleading. | |
172 | + | |
173 | +\begin{table}[ht] | |
174 | +\centering | |
175 | + % \captionof{table}{Fictitious data about the trade flows between | |
176 | + % countries $X$, $Y$ and $Z$. The box around numerical values indicate | |
177 | + % that the trade takes place under an FTA.} | |
178 | + \caption{Naive calculation of the growth rates under and outside FTAs | |
179 | + for the data already reported in Table \ref{tradeexample}.}\label{tradetable} | |
180 | +\scalebox{1}{ | |
181 | +\begin{tabular}{|r|l|l|l|r|} | |
182 | + \hline | |
183 | +Year & 2013 & 2014 & 2015 & 2016 \\ | |
184 | + \hline | |
185 | +$l_{XY}$ & \boxed{5} & \boxed{5.2} & \boxed{5.1} & \boxed{5.6} \\ | |
186 | + $l_{YZ}$ & 10 & 10.4 & 11.2 & 12.1 \\ | |
187 | + $l_{XZ}$ & 8 & 8.3 & \boxed{8.1} & \boxed{8.7} \\ | |
188 | + \hline | |
189 | + Total FTA Trade & 5 & 5.2 & 13.2 & 14.3 \\ | |
190 | + Total non-FTA Trade & 18 & 18.7 & 11.2 & 12.1 \\ | |
191 | + \hline | |
192 | + Naive FTA growth rate & & 4{\% } & 154{\% } & 8{\% } \\ | |
193 | + Naive non-FTA growth rate & & 4{\% } & -40{\% } & 8{\% } \\ | |
194 | + \hline | |
195 | +\end{tabular} | |
196 | +} | |
197 | +\end{table} | |
198 | + | |
199 | +\section{Amended Calculation for (non-)FTA Trade Flows} | |
200 | + | |
201 | +One possible solution is simply not to include $l_{XZ}$ in 2015 in the | |
202 | +calculations, i.e. to remove the trade flow which transitions from | |
203 | +non-FTA to FTA in the year of implementation of the FTA, whereas | |
204 | +including it in all the calculations for the previous and the | |
205 | +following year does not pose any problem. | |
206 | + | |
207 | +Another tackle on this issue is to calculate the growth rates in 2015 | |
208 | +as if in 2014 (the year before the FTA kicked in) $l_{XY}$ was already | |
209 | +covered by the FTA. Indeed the idea is | |
210 | +to artificially shift the FTAs by one year in such a way to get more | |
211 | +sensible results. | |
212 | + | |
213 | + | |
214 | +As a consequence we create, only for the | |
215 | +calculations of the growth rate for 2015, an ``artificial'' year 2014 | |
216 | +where the trade flow $l_{XZ}$ is already counted as being part of the | |
217 | +FTA trade. | |
218 | + | |
219 | + | |
220 | + | |
221 | +\begin{table}[ht] | |
222 | +\centering | |
223 | + % \captionof{table}{Fictitious data about the trade flows between | |
224 | + % countries $X$, $Y$ and $Z$. The box around numerical values indicate | |
225 | + % that the trade takes place under an FTA.} | |
226 | + \caption{Creation of an artificial 2014 year to fix the calculations of | |
227 | + the growth rate. In the artificial 2014, $l_{XZ}$ is already | |
228 | + considered part of the trade under FTA.}\label{tradetablefixed} | |
229 | +\scalebox{1}{ | |
230 | +\begin{tabular}{|r|l|l|l|l|r|} | |
231 | + \hline | |
232 | +Year & 2013 & 2014 & 2014 artificial & 2015 & 2016 \\ | |
233 | + \hline | |
234 | +$l_{XY}$ & \boxed{5} & \boxed{5.2} & \boxed{5.2} & \boxed{5.1} & \boxed{5.6} \\ | |
235 | + $l_{YZ}$ & 10 & 10.4 & 10.4 & 11.2 & 12.1 \\ | |
236 | + $l_{XZ}$ & 8 & 8.3 & \boxed{8.3} & \boxed{8.1} & \boxed{8.7} \\ | |
237 | + \hline | |
238 | + Total FTA Trade & 5 & 5.2 & 13.5 & 13.2 & 14.3 \\ | |
239 | + Total non-FTA Trade & 18 & 18.7 & 10.4 & 11.2 & 12.1 \\ | |
240 | + \hline | |
241 | + Naive FTA growth rate & & 4{\% } & & 154{\% } & 8{\% } \\ | |
242 | + Naive non-FTA growth rate & & 4{\% } & & -40{\% } & 8{\% } \\ | |
243 | + \hline | |
244 | + New FTA growth rate & & 4{\% } & & -2{\% } & 8{\% } \\ | |
245 | + New non-FTA growth rate & & 4{\% } & & 8{\% } & 8{\% } \\ | |
246 | + \hline | |
247 | +\end{tabular} | |
248 | +} | |
249 | +\end{table} | |
250 | + | |
251 | +The proposed workaround is illustrated in Table | |
252 | +\ref{tradetablefixed}. We notice | |
253 | +that, with respect to the naive calculation of the growth rates under | |
254 | +FTAs, this proposed remedy differs only for the year 2015, when an FTA | |
255 | +is enforced, but it provides much more sensible results. | |
256 | +The same strategy can be generalised in case of multiple FTAs being | |
257 | +enforced on the same year. | |
258 | + | |
259 | +An equivalent way of describing this procedure is the following: whenever at | |
260 | +time $t$ a certain trade flow is covered by an FTA, we calculate its | |
261 | +growth rate by assuming that at time $t-1$ it was already covered by | |
262 | +the FTA. | |
263 | + | |
264 | +Once we have got the yearly growth rates, we can calculate the | |
265 | +annualized growth rate according to | |
266 | +Eq. \eqref{composite}-\eqref{annualized} both of the trade under FTAs | |
267 | + | |
268 | +\begin{equation} | |
269 | +g_{\mathrm{FTA}}^{2014-2016}=\{(1+4\% )\times (1-2\% )\times (1+8\% )\}^{1/3}-1=3\% | |
270 | +\end{equation} | |
271 | +and outside FTAs | |
272 | + | |
273 | +\begin{equation} | |
274 | +g_{\mathrm{non-FTA}}^{2014-2016}=\{ (1+4\% )\times(1+8\% ) \times(1+8\% ) \}^{1/3}-1=7\%. | |
275 | +\end{equation} | |
276 | +% Finally, once we have calculated the correct yearly growth rates, we resort to | |
277 | +% Eq. \eqref{composite} to get the total growth rate along the a period | |
278 | +% consisting of multiple years. | |
279 | + | |
280 | +Our strategy is formally analogous to the calculation | |
281 | +of the returns of a portfolio in the presence of cash deposits | |
282 | +and cash withdrawals (see | |
283 | + | |
284 | +\href{https://www.fool.com/about/how-to-calculate-investment-returns/}{https://www.fool.com/about/how-to-calculate-investment-returns/} | |
285 | +and | |
286 | + | |
287 | +\href{https://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/annualized-total-return.asp}{https://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/annualized-total-return.asp}): | |
288 | +signing an FTA means metaphorically depositing the associated trade | |
289 | +flows into the portfolio of FTA trade while simultaneously removing them | |
290 | +from the non-FTA trade portfolio. | |
291 | + | |
292 | + The idea is to obtain the growth rate of | |
293 | +FTA vs non-FTA trade in a way which is not affected by the shift of | |
294 | +trade flows due to new FTA agreements. In the portfolio management | |
295 | +analogy, we want to calculate the real performance of the portfolio | |
296 | +due to the investment choices and without the effects of cash deposits | |
297 | +and/or withdrawals. | |
298 | +% The link above also tells how to construct, from the individual growth | |
299 | +% rates, a growth rate along the whole period (it goes without saying | |
300 | +% that the simple addition and/or average of the growth rates along | |
301 | +% different years is not an appropriate method, see also | |
302 | + | |
303 | +% \href{https://investinganswers.com/financial-dictionary/investing/average-annual-growth-rate-aagr-2549}{https://investinganswers.com/financial-dictionary/investing/average-annual-growth-rate-aagr-2549}. ) | |
304 | + | |
305 | + | |
306 | + | |
307 | + | |
308 | + | |
309 | +\end{document} | |
310 | + | |
311 | +%%% Local Variables: | |
312 | +%%% mode: latex | |
313 | +%%% TeX-master: t | |
314 | +%%% End: |